Some time ago, I had a
discussion with a colleague on the alignment of interest in hedge funds.
Understandably, the discussion focused on the design of fee structures, and on
performance fees in particular. For any decent investment size, fees are
normally negotiable, and it is up to the investor and fund manager to agree
upon a fair level. The final deal is dependent on the negotiating power of the
two parties and the particular circumstances of the investment (such as
seeding, size, lock-up, capacity, and so on).
Having agreed that the fee levels are a question
for negotiation, we discussed whether there were any possible flaws in the
overall design of the fee model. Are there situations where the manager could
game the fee design, thereby possibly misaligning the interests of the investor
and the fund manager?
The answer is yes. Opportunities for misalignment
exist, but there are relatively easy remedies.
For many hedge funds, at least smaller ones, the
fixed fees are needed to cover running costs of operations. The true upside
potential comes from performance fees, so receiving these fees regularly enough
is desirable. Here lies the root of a possible issue.
“The
randomised model could be useful, as it helps to identify potential loopholes
in the standard model. And if anything needs a thought experiment, it is fees.”
Imagine the
following situation: The manager has had a very good start to a quarter and the
quarter-end is approaching. The performance fee will be crystallised at the
quarter-end, but there are still two weeks to go. Is it not conceivable that
the manager feels tempted to start playing it safe in order to guard the
performance fee? The manager might reduce the risk of the positions or even get
out of some of the riskier positions, not because he needs to do that from an
investment risk/return perspective, but because he is optimising his fees.
However, assuming that the opportunity set is unchanged, he should probably
maintain his original positions. Failing to do so will reduce the long-term
return of his portfolio, contrary to his clients’ interests.
Whether imaginary or not, there are easy ways to
resolve the quarter-end problem. One idea is to randomise the day on which the
performance fee is calculated. A simple method is, after the end of the
quarter, to randomly select a month-end within the quarter in a controlled
fashion. The performance fee—and high-water mark (HWM)—is based on the net
asset value (NAV) at that month-end. So if we are in the second quarter and
April is drawn, the performance fee and HWM would be based on the April
reading. Neither the manager nor the investor controls the random number
generation; the number is drawn by a third party—for example, the fund
administrator. The possible performance fee would still be paid after the
quarter-end, as before, the only difference being that the fee is calculated
based on the performance at the randomly determined month-end. Alternatively,
one could randomise even further by drawing a random day within the quarter,
but with the need to strike intra-month NAVs, this might get over-complicated.
Over time, the random method would not change the
overall performance fee earned/paid, so neither the manager nor the investor
would be favoured or penalised. Admittedly, there is the added complication and
cost caused by administering the random number-draw. The method might also lead
to occasional unintuitive fee payments; for example, a performance fee might be
earned (because of good intra-quarter results) during a negative quarter or
vice versa. But as the role of the quarter-end as the measurement day has been
abolished, the temptation for playing safe is reduced.
Nothing is completely straightforward. Firstly,
some incentives to game the quarterly figures remain despite randomising. A
manager still wants to achieve a good quarterly ranking in the various hedge
fund databases. Even some investors might prefer the manager playing it safe,
because of quarterly performance reporting and their own career risk.
Secondly, there are situations where reducing risk
around certain dates is based on a truly changed opportunity set or an altered
risk/return trade-off. Examples include the release of important economic data,
uncertainty around elections, and year-end US congressional decisions on debt
ceilings.
Thirdly, there might be simpler ways to avoid the
possible conflict of interests. A natural solution would be to increase the
transparency given for clients. For managed accounts, the transparency is
already there.
Still, as a
thought experiment, the randomised model could be useful, as it helps to
identify some of the potential loopholes in the standard model. And if anything
needs a thought experiment, it is fees.
—Erik Valtonen is CEO of Blue Diamond Asset Management, a
hedge fund based in Pfäffikon, Switzerland. He was formerly the CIO of Swedish
pension buffer fund AP3.